Aziz Sunderji - The Forces Keeping Home Prices High
Welcome back to Home Economics, a newsletter about the American housing market. Below my brief comments, today’s guest post is by economist Cameron Murray, author of The Great Housing Hijack and the Substack newsletter Fresh Economic Thinking. I asked Murray to write a guest post for Home Economics because, living up to the title of his newsletter, he brings some fresh thinking to the discussion around the high home prices we see across the world today. Murray’s arguments seem to attract both devoted followers and fierce dissent. This is, at least, the hallmark of someone taking a clear view and injecting some fresh thinking into the debate. I hope you find his words here thought provoking. Cameron Murray writes: In The Great Housing Hijack I outline the five equilibrium forces that determine property: (1) prices, (2) rents, (3) their spatial variation, (4) density, and (5) the rate of new production. These matter. Too many contributors to the academic and public debate on housing have little economic notion of where prices come from, or why property markets deliver certain outcomes. Grab your copy of the book here. What’s an equilibrium?To get started in understanding these forces we need to understand the logic of trade and equilibrium pressures. Consider the below image of two supermarket checkout queues. Because people can swap (trade) queues this situation is not an equilibrium. There is an arbitrage opportunity for the people at the back of the long queue to swap and get checked out more quickly. The below shows these trades and the resulting equilibrium checkout queue length. Will checkout lengths always be exactly equal? No. But they cannot stay far from this equilibrium point for long and the force of trading choice keeps the lengths tied to this outcome. Equilibrium is a fundamental idea in economics. But it is often applied haphazardly. My approach to housing markets refines our understanding of equilibrium forces driven by trading choices that constrain property market outcomes and looks at these forces across the many economic dimensions involved in property markets and housing. Where do home prices come from?Most people would say supply and demand. That’s a start. But it doesn’t tell us much more than that sellers and buyers agreed to prices. I mean, who else sets the price? Supply and demand is merely a description of market price adjustment. It doesn’t tell us why buyers were willing to pay a certain price, nor why sellers want to sell and are willing to accept that price. It doesn’t tell us anything about the broader equilibrium trading forces in the market. The trick to understanding property asset market prices (yes, housing is an asset) is that every dollar spent on a home can be spent on any other asset in the economy. Homes can’t be priced for long at a level whereby the return on a dollar invested in housing is far out of whack with the rates of return on a dollar invested elsewhere. The rate of return from rents and capital gains on housing must track closely the prevailing rates of return in other asset markets over the long term. This is why monetary policy, whereby the interest rate on bank deposits is lowered or increased, has a substantial effect on home buying and prices. Lower returns on cash assets make the returns on housing at the prevailing price seem more attractive. To use the checkout analogy, money leaves the cash queue and goes to the housing queue. Vice-versa when interest rates rise (though there are longer lags and more price stickiness when it comes to declining asset prices). An easy way to think about this equilibrium relationship with other assets is that homebuyers can either rent a home from a landlord or rent money to become their own landlord. Where do rents come from?If housing asset prices come from equilibrium forces that ensure rates of return can’t diverge much from other asset markets, where do rents come from that determine that return on housing? Rental equilibrium forces come from the trade-off between spending an extra dollar of household income on rent or an extra dollar on other goods and services. Many people think that this means that with enough extra housing, rents will fall as a share of income across the market. This is wrong. Yes, spending a smaller share of income over time does happen for many goods, like food and clothing, where demand is easily saturated. But not housing. As incomes rise, households tend to do one or more of the following.
Because a better location is a relative concept, there is a type of tournament economy for the best-ranked locations. Across the market, people compete in that tournament to climb the ranks of relatively superior locations until they spend roughly a fixed share of their income on housing rent. Surprisingly, because of these adjustments in household composition and location, the actual quantity of dwellings and people is not so important for determining this rental equilibrium. A few decades ago when there were 3 people per dwelling on average in small homes, and now when there are 2.5 people on average in large homes, this equilibrium seems to hold. And we do see that in the United States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand, rent-to-income ratios have been flat for many decades, as expected. In fact, in Australia’s first inquiry into rising rents in Sydney back in 1911 rents were then 20% of income, the same as 110 years later in 2021. Here are some charts. The only way to get rents to fall below this equilibrium is to limit the ability of renters to try and move to better locations (to trade or swap queues). This is the same way we can make the supermarket checkout queue shorter—stop people from the long queue trying to trade into the short one. Another insight from the rental equilibrium is that inflation in non-housing goods means that renter households can pay more for rent because that means giving up fewer other goods and services for an extra quantity or quality of housing. This is the opposite of what many people might expect. Some might think that if goods and services have risen in price then households have less left over for rent, so rents should fall when there is inflation. This is wrong. Spatial equilibriumWhy are rents higher in some places and not in others? The answer is that there is an equilibrium in another dimension—across space (or location). People can move to different locations and will do so if the value of that move exceeds the extra cost of housing at that location. The ability to swap queues—from one location to another—means that the difference in rents between locations reflects the total quality of life difference between locations. The example below is from my book The Great Housing Hijack. Here, the Jones family values living in House A at a prime location at $600 and the identical House B at an inferior location at $350 based on their own household’s preferences, work and family needs. The Lee family values House A at $700 and House B at $350. If the Lees lived in House B and the Joneses in House A, they could swap homes and both be better off. Alternatively, if both homes were owned by another landlord, the Lees would end up renting House A at $700 and the Joneses House B at $400. The $300 difference in rent for the identical home at a different location is the market assessment of the relative value of each location. This is why I think many renters argue against gentrification. They think these local investments will make their location relatively more desirable to others and that they will then have to pay higher rents to compete with others just to stay put. What determines housing density?There are many debates about how densely we should develop cities. But too often economics analysis is missing. Density is another dimension where there are equilibrium forces in property markets. Before a project is built, there are multiple queues—less dense or more dense. The queue that maximizes the net value to the property owner is the one that is the equilibrium density. This equilibrium force affects physical housing outcomes only at the time a new housing project is being irreversibly committed to. All previous times do have an optimal density, but that doesn’t mean that housing at that density will be built. The basic logic arises because there are diseconomies in constructing higher-density projects. To build a home worth the same value at a higher density requires more capital. This is easy to visualize with high-rise apartments. The tallest ones happen only in high-value areas because the extra high value of an extra apartment can cover the extra cost of going higher. But the principle applies just as well to detached housing subdivisions, townhouses and low-rise blocks. You keep testing whether more density leaves you more value left over after necessary capital investments until you maximise that residual. It is important to note here that every home has the “wrong” density as soon as it is completed. Markets change and so does the density that maximises value to the property owner. It is also true that many different density projects can be feasible at a particular time (i.e. the net value of a housing project after capital costs exceeds the value of the current use of the property). Out of all the feasible projects, the one with the highest residual value is the highest value use. How quickly should new homes be built?It is common to think that all feasible homes are immediately built and this is why we need to change the planning system to create more feasible housing development locations. That is wrong. Generally, there is an enormous pool of feasible housing projects either approved or allowable in the planning system. For example, in Queensland (Australia) where I live, there are likely many millions of apartments that are feasible and allowable. Currently, there are 125,000 apartments with planning approval. But only about 6,000 apartments are built per year. The rate of housing production out of the pool of feasible projects is regulated by a market equilibrium as well—the absorption rate equilibrium. To pick up the supermarket checkout analogy again, the two queues are 1) build today or 2) build in the future. The rate at which projects shift queues is the rate at which new homes are developed. When new home buying slows down, rather than decrease prices to keep selling and building new homes at the same rate, property owners also slow sales and delay more homes. And in a boom, they bring forward projects to meet rising homebuying. Making projects feasible does not mean they will be built today. They might be more feasible tomorrow!¹ So what?Housing debates often ignore these fundamental economic equilibrium forces. Many people think we can make rents fall in a single city by creating more feasible new housing projects there, ignoring the rental, spatial, and absorption rate equilibria. The diagram below shows how density and the rate of new housing production (the absorption rate) are distinct concepts, but too often confused. We can build four new homes per year at low or high density, or build eight new homes per year at low or high density. Most people assume that creating more high-density feasible projects means that not only will density increase, but the rate of housing production (the absorption rate) will too. For some reason, they slip a hidden assumption into the word supply that a fixed number of projects must happen each year, and the more homes in each project, the faster we get more homes. If we want to change housing policy, the least we should do is first understand how property markets work and what outcomes are possible. 1 I highly recommend this detailed article on the topic of optimal delay in housing production Home Economics is a reader-supported publication. Please consider upgrading to a paid subscription to support our work. Paying clients receive access to the full archive, forecasts, data sets, and exclusive in-depth analysis. This edition is free—you can forward it to colleagues who appreciate concise, data-driven housing analysis. |
Older messages
Why Housing Watchers Should Learn Python Programming
Tuesday, December 3, 2024
A showcase with housing and migration data ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Five Innovations that Could Upend the Housing Market
Wednesday, November 20, 2024
Don't overlook technology's role in shaping housing demand–and supply. Here are five technologies that will make a difference. ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Happy News
Tuesday, November 5, 2024
Paternity leave and guest authors ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
The Week in Review
Sunday, October 20, 2024
Week of Oct 7 — Buyers brighten, inflation eases ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
The Week in Review
Saturday, October 5, 2024
Week of Sept 30th — Payrolls pop ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
You Might Also Like
#66: What The Notches Said – No. 06
Wednesday, January 15, 2025
Interview with 'Z', who's from my səxual past ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Katie Holmes’ Monochrome Outfit Debuts Winter’s New *It* Color
Wednesday, January 15, 2025
We're major fans. The Zoe Report Daily The Zoe Report 1.14.2025 Katie Holmes' Monochrome Outfit Debuts Winter's New *It* Color (Celebrity) Katie Holmes' Monochrome Outfit Debuts
The Best Thing: January 14, 2025
Wednesday, January 15, 2025
The Best Thing is our weekly discussion thread where we share the one thing that we read, listened to, watched, did, or otherwise enjoyed recent… ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
'Micro-Dosing' Your Concealer Is The Genius Hack For Flawless Skin
Wednesday, January 15, 2025
A celebrity makeup artist breaks it down. The Zoe Report Beauty The Zoe Report 1.14.2025 (Beauty) lisa eldridge pinpoint concealer micro correcting pencil (Makeup) 'Micro-Dosing' Your Concealer
How to Use TikTok in the US, Even When It's Banned
Tuesday, January 14, 2025
9 States Will Have Lower Income Taxes This Year. Even if TikTok is banned, there are ways to access it. Not displaying correctly? View this newsletter online. TODAY'S FEATURED STORY How to Use
Keke Palmer’s Greatest Role Is Herself
Tuesday, January 14, 2025
Today in style, self, culture, and power. The Cut January 14, 2025 CUT COVERS Keke Palmer's Greatest Role Is Herself How the former child star became a multimedia mogul and stopped trying to please
A Deleted 'SATC' Scene Explains Charlotte & Trey's Divorce Twist
Tuesday, January 14, 2025
Plus, Every time Anne Hathaway freed the nipple, your daily horoscope, and more. Jan. 14, 2025 Bustle Daily Y2K trends are back, but what happened to the optimism? BOOKS Y2K Trends Are Back, But What
Why I didn't save my kitchen during the LA fire evacuation
Tuesday, January 14, 2025
Are TikTokers putting beef tallow on their faces?
New from Tim — My First Book In 7+ Years (Plus “Tactics and Strategies for a 2025 Reboot”)
Tuesday, January 14, 2025
The latest from author and investor Tim Ferriss ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Demi Moore Continues To Reinvent Herself
Tuesday, January 14, 2025
Plus: Zendaya leans into the chaos of her characters. • Jan. 14, 2025 Up Next Your complete guide to industry-shaping entertainment news, exclusive interviews with A-list celebs, and what you should