When IBM Was The Center of Gravity
Plus! Price Signals; Texas Energy's Banking Crisis; Greensill's Arbitrage(s); Which Long Run?; The Supply-Side/Demand-Side Seesaw
Byrne Hobart | Mar 5 |
This is the free edition of The Diff. This week's subscribers-only posts were in a series on "compounders" that stopped compounding. Each one is a post-mortem on a company that produced above-average growth for a decade or more, and then produced zero or negative returns for a decade after that.
To read these, and access the full back catalogue, you can support The Diff and subscribe today. When IBM Was The Center of GravityPlus! Price Signals; Texas Energy's Banking Crisis; Greensill's Arbitrage(s); Which Long Run?; The Supply-Side/Demand-Side Seesaw
This is the once-a-week free edition of The Diff, the newsletter about inflections in finance and technology. The free edition goes out to 20,611 subscribers, up 125 since the last edition. In this issue:
IBM: The Center of GravityLearning about IBM in the context of the early history of the computer industry has the same shock value as watching Star Wars: A New Hope for the first time: "That's no moon. It's a space station." Consider:
In "Adam Smith"'s wonderful book, The Money Game, the concept of a growth stock is illustrated with a five-year table of some high growth companies' earnings per share; IBM is at the top of the list. More interesting is an earlier section on investor psychology, which has a bit called "IBM as Religion: Don't Touch, Don't Touch." It's a story about someone who invests in IBM's predecessor, Computing-Tabulating-Recording Company, and holds the stock for his entire life. His $20,000 becomes millions of dollars, and he insists that his heirs never sell the stock. They don’t, and they make the same stipulation to their heirs. One reason for the company's marvelous performance is, of course, that it retains most of its earnings and pays low dividends. When he dies, the stock is split up between his heirs, who also hold and never sell, and who also end up as millionaires, as do their heirs. But the dividends remain modest:
How did IBM get so dominant? How did "Nobody ever got fired for buying IBM," become a catchphrase among corporate IT buyers and investors? And what changed? Origins: Promoters and Punch-cardsIn 2021's SPAC-saturated financial universe (and in light of the last few weeks' SPAC drawdowns), it's interesting to note that IBM was born as an act of financial engineering. In the early 1900s, the market was enamored by trusts, and promoters realized that merging a few semi-related companies together could create a combined entity that was a) big enough to issue stock, and b) could tell a plausible story that it would monopolize its industry. (Monopolies were technically illegal, but in practice weren't heavily prosecuted. The existence of the Sherman Antitrust Act told investors that a monopolist could charge exploitative prices; its lax enforcement told them that it wouldn't be shut down for this reason.) Charles Flint was one of many stock promoters who merged together small companies and took them public. In 1911, he cobbled together a new firm called Computing-Tabulating-Recording Company. CTR was an odd mix, including an industrial scale manufacturer, a company that made timecards for hourly workers, and The Tabulating Machine Company. The last was a quirky niche product: founded by a German inventor, Herman Hollerith, it built mechanical devices that could tabulate information if it was encoded on punched cards. The company had only a handful of customers; railroads, for example, could save money and better track their business using punched cards. The company's most important client was the US Census, but one big contract every ten years did not indicate much business potential. As it turns out, the company made one other key acquisition: hiring Thomas J. Watson as President. Watson had a somewhat mixed reputation: he'd worked for National Cash Register, a company that was famous for rapid growth, technical sophistication, and an excellent sales organization.² On the other hand, he'd been recently convicted of antitrust violations for some of his work at NCR, and faced jail time. Flint, perhaps operating on the assumption that he'd sell out of the stock before the case was fully resolved, hired Watson anyway. Watson had a natural flair for sales and strategy, and had developed his sales technique at NCR. NCR deployed armies of salespeople, held them all to strict personal standards (good grooming, no alcohol consumption whatsoever), and used this standardized approach to scale fast. Watson’s CTR adopted the same model, and even borrowed some of the same mottos: One realization Watson came to was that CTR was a clunky name, and, as trusts went out of fashion, was sending the wrong signal to the market (and to the FTC). So, in 1924, he renamed the company International Business Machines. Watson also insisted on reinvesting in the business, even though other executives like board chairman George W. Fairchild were more concerned with maintaining dividends.³ He came to another important realization about one of those business machines in particular: Hollerith's punched-card tabulators were more exciting than they looked, especially for an organization that specialized in sales. The machines themselves had unimpressive margins, but making stacks of perforated cardboard and selling them to a captive market was a very high-margin business indeed. And this sticky, high-margin revenue source grew with usage, not just the unit volume of tabulators. If IBM could embed its salespeople in companies, and have them relentlessly THINK about ways to replace clerks with cards (or about new functions that could be economically performed by cards but that wouldn't be worth an employee's time), they could continuously grow sales. By the 1930s, cards routinely represented a third of sales, and presumably a much larger share of profits. IBM's sales were flat early in the depression, as cuts in corporate spending were offset by growth in government use. During the Second World War, IBM continued to grow its top line—profits were compressed by higher taxes—but it also reinforced a virtuous cycle. More tabulated data meant more legible data; the Social Security Administration was a big client, but also a client whose existence gave every American a unique numerical identifier, and whose implementation meant that their employers had to track who them employed and how much each one was paid. Heavy war spending required more data tracking, and this meant that manufacturers also needed to invest in business machines to meet their end of the bargain. Even later, when IBM was less dependent on cards, it liked the model of having a long tail of revenue. As IBM evolved, it preferred to lease its products rather than sell them, and to offer peripherals that would increase revenue per customer. Even after cards were irrelevant, a card-like model was a core part of IBM: each year, they started with a baseline of high-margin recurring revenue from existing clients. New sales would just add to that sum. DominanceIBM was not the first company to build computers, although Thomas Watson Jr., who took over from his father in 1952, was certainly interested in them. Sperry-Rand's subsidiary UNIVAC (which survives today as Unisys) introduced the first commercially successful computers in the early 50s.⁴ IBM had the largest R&D department of the business machines industry in the 40s and 50s, and Watson had read Norbert Wiener's Cybernetics. IBM quickly caught up, and had dominant market share in computers by the late 1950s. Some of this was because of their research—they were able to introduce cost-competitive computers a few years after UNIVAC. And a lot of it was because of their sales organization: IBM sales reps didn't have to introduce themselves to potential corporate customers, who had been buying other IBM products for years or possibly decades. IBM added another tactic around this time, which would be called "paper machines" then and "vaporware" today: if a competitor's product was selling well because it reached a price or market segment that IBM didn’t touch, the company wouldn't hesitate to announce a competing product (and start taking orders for it) long before it was available. Meanwhile, IBM kept news about upgrades to its existing products well-hidden. This sort of behavior led to one of what would be a long series of unpleasant interactions with the Justice Department, leading to a decree in 1956 that required IBM to divest some of its punched-card business and start selling as well as leasing computers. This is an early case study of a common phenomenon: antitrust cases take so long—in part because the companies being sued are not especially cooperative—that by the time they're resolved, the industry has changed, and the remedies don’t have much of an impact. IBM had to divest a rapidly-shrinking segment that was quickly being rendered obsolete by the company's other products. It's hard to overstate how powerful IBM was in the computer industry by this time. A big order from IBM revived Texas Instruments' fortunes in the late 50s, for example, and every computer company worried that if their product worked too well for too long, it was only a matter of time before an army in a uniform of starched white shirts, blue suits, clean shaves, and high quotas was marching on their customers and offering a more expensive, but much more defensible, choice. Both IBM and its competitors acknowledged that the company excelled at sales. As the CEO of UNIVAC's parent company put it:
And in a revealing comment from Watson, Jr., he once explained that the company's release cadence was dictated in part by the needs of its sales team:
One of the biggest New Things IBM fed to its salesmen in the 60s was the 360. This product, announced in 1964 and first sold the next year, was IBM's most intensive development project in history, costing, according to one estimate, twice as much as the Manhattan Project. The 360 was a series of machines that had compatible code, so customers could easily upgrade from one to the next as they scaled without needing to rewrite their software. It was, in other words, another way for IBM to replicate the negative dollar churn model of the punched card business. IBM needed the 360 in part because its sales team was entirely too good: the people responsible for selling IBM's low-end machines were cannibalizing the sales of high-end ones by convincing buyers that the more affordable option could handle all of their needs. While the 360 represented a technological advance, it was partly an organizational one—a way to give the company a strict hierarchy of products and use cases so it could charge what the market would bear. IBM had to repeatedly turn to the capital markets to fund this, although the company kept reporting growing profits throughout the development process. The launch of the 360 represents Peak IBM in terms of influence and ability to shape markets, although their financial peak was a long way off. IBM's computers were so successful that they spawned two separate ecosystems: the first "IBM compatible" devices were produced in the 1950s, when smaller manufacturers sold peripherals that functioned alongside IBM machines. More worrisome for the company was the trend of computer leasing companies, whose business model was straightforward: IBM depreciated its computers over five years, and priced them accordingly. Leasing companies depreciated computers over ten years, and were able to undercut IBM and report (accounting) profits doing it. These leasing companies would have slightly worse cash flows than IBM, since their higher reported profits entailed a higher tax burden. But they were able to show good profits, and as long as they grew fast enough, any misguided optimism about the useful life of a computer would be hidden. (If a leasing company grows its assets 50% each year, and the IBM depreciation number is correct, then the computers they start to write down in year six are just a fifth of assets, and they've had five years of profitable growth before then.) Paradoxically, the leasing companies (some of which were much hotter stocks than IBM in the 60s) were a bet on growth but against technology. An investor buying IBM instead of Leasco was betting that the 360 was not the last word in computing (and that whatever the last word was, it would be spoken in the vicinity of Armonk, New York). A buyer of Leasco was implicitly claiming that the computer trend had been an interesting one, and had fully run its course by the mid-60s, with deployment rather than new technology as the main source of growth. In a sense, the company painted itself into a corner: by creating a new standard, and ensuring that future releases would be backwards-compatible, IBM plausibly did increase the useful life of its computers. The company could either cut leasing rates (which would cut into revenue) or accept that its model was shifting from leasing computers to customers over to selling them to middlemen. IBM did adjust its pricing, but this entailed still more problems. DeclineIn 1968, Control Data accused IBM of assorted antitrust violations, which the US government followed up on the next year. IBM spent over a decade in litigation, hiring armies of lawyers and producing millions of documents. (The joke at the time was that the real winner of the case was Xerox.) The case ran on long enough that IBM could accurately argue that more than half of the companies that accused it of anticompetitive behavior had been founded after the original lawsuit was filed. Some companies bet their future on IBM in yet another way; the CEO of one company, Calcomp, joked that his company's most valuable asset wasn't patents, equipment, or employees, but their ongoing lawsuit against IBM. The suit was ultimately dropped, but IBM's defense was all too accurate: the computer business was getting too competitive, and other companies were adapting faster than IBM itself was. Over the course of the 70s, IBM's annual profits still tripled, but by the end of the decade, the stock hadn’t gone up at all. The story of IBM's long-term collapse was not the result of any one decision; if there was one bad decision, it was the way they structured their MS-DOS deal, which allowed Microsoft to license it to other PC manufacturers. But that choice was more symptomatic. IBM's sales centric approach naturally assumed a slower industry cadence than the one that developed in the 80s. Rapid growth in low-end computers reduced the relevance of their competitive advantage in large-scale, long-term deals, and as those computers got more powerful, software started to matter more. A pure software company has higher margins, and thus more ability to take risky bets, than a software-and-hardware company, particularly one that's constantly adjusting its overhead in light of lower and lower market share. IBM was the most profitable company in America in 1985, but by the early 90s, IBM was losing money. It reported what was then a record annual loss for any US corporation in 1992. The company eventually stabilized, by divesting some money-losing businesses and focusing more on corporate clients. (It also started to focus more on buybacks, even though an early buyback program in the 80s was one reason IBM was somewhat capital-constrained at the dawn of the PC era.) It's exceptionally hard for a company to adjust to no longer dominating its industry. That's especially difficult when the nature of the industry changes; caring about PCs was low-status relative to worrying about mainframes until the growth of the PC market was impossible to ignore. Relative to the other stories of compounders-gone-bad, IBM ends up being the most impressive of the lot. It had an incredible stretch of nonstop growth, and that stretch started after the company pivoted from one sector it was influential in, punched-card machines, to a completely new one it had to catch up in. IBM's ability to keep growing while disrupting itself, and juggling antitrust restrictions, is simply astounding. While it's not nearly as influential as it once was, there was indeed a good reason that, for a very long time, nobody got fired for buying IBM. A Word From Our SponsorsDiff readers want to know everything worth reading in finance and technology. But some of us want to know everything that’s worth reading about everything. The best place to start is The Browser, a curated newsletter of five fascinating stories each day on every topic imaginable, from how Aztecs thought about pandemics to how novelists write from the perspective of chickens. I’m a regular reader, and The Browser has featured a few Diff pieces in the past. I encourage you to sign up here—Diff readers get 20% off your first year with the code DIFF20 at checkout. ElsewherePrice SignalsSince the Drake Well was drilled in 1859, oil has been in one of two price regimes: it's either one of the most volatile asset classes on earth, because supply responds to demand on a lag, or it's surprisingly sedate because a single swing producer or buyer keeps things in check. Who keeps volatility in check has changed over time: originally it was Standard Oil, which gradually squeezed speculation out of the market. Then it was the Texas Railroad Commission, until Texas ran out of spare capacity, and after that it was Saudi Arabia. Now, arguably, it's US capital markets: fracking is more demand-responsive than other kinds of oil, because fracked oil doesn't produce as long as conventional. When capital markets reward growth, US oil production rockets. Right now, at least on the equity side, US energy investors are very reluctant to subsidize growth. Oil majors are promising to go carbon-neutral, while smaller frackers are making the slightly less inspiring promise that they'll pay dividends and buy back stock rather than drill so frenetically. But privately-held oil companies don't have that constraint, and some of them want to take advantage of higher prices by raising production. Texas Energy's Banking CrisisIn last Friday's post, I noted that one layer of the electrical grid is basically a bank: companies commit to providing electricity to end users, and they buy it on wholesale markets. This is basically borrowing short and lending long, a strategy that is generally profitable but sometimes blows up. (In this case, it did.) Texas' grid operator, ERCOT, may unwind $16bn of these purchases ($, FT), which would rescue some insolvent companies at the cost of complicating the next power shortage. It's always tempting to void trades that are made at extreme prices. Clearly, no one thought that $9,000/MWh was a sensible price when the usual cost is more like $25. On the other hand, some businesses are only viable because they can provide a product in extreme cases, and the more such businesses there are, the fewer the extreme pricing swings. In other financial markets, breaking trades doesn't lead to lower volatility: it just tells market-makers to stop participating when prices get extreme, which tends to cause more extreme swings (and can lead to markets that don't clear at all). It's a second-order solution with third-order consequences, but the first-order problem is an inability to handle particular kinds of weather events. Greensill's Arbitrage(s)I wrote on Monday about the collapse of trade finance company Greensill. (See this Net Interest post for an overview of the company.) FT has more details on how it happened: an insurance company that had been insuring Greensill's loans declined to renew their policy, and Greensill couldn't find another insurer ($). This makes their prior valuation a bit easier to understand, in theory: Greensill was able to offer financial products that were close to risk-free, and had better yields than cash, because they were adroit at shifting risk to other parties. But that risk-free-ness turned out to be something they'd have to renew repeatedly, so as soon as it wasn't available, the rest of their model failed. Another thing Greensill did was provide capital to other companies that had raised from Softbank, like the troubled construction startup Katerra. The Information has an excellent piece on Katerra's issues ($), and one thing that comes up is that Katerra was aggressive about recognizing revenue early. A company that pulls revenue from the future without collecting cash payments as fast will be in perennial need of funds, and Greensill seems to have helped keep them liquid. In principle, there's nothing wrong with an investor encouraging portfolio companies to do business with one another; it can be part of their value-add. But at least optically, this looks like a more pathological form of that practice. Which Long Run?AQR has another great paper on thinking about factor returns.⁵ In this piece, Cliff Asness breaks returns down into changes in valuation and changes in everything else, and uses this to argue that a) high US equity returns relative to the rest of the world won't persist forever, and b) value strategies' relatively poor performance also won't persist forever. It's a good framework. You can divide the returns from a fundamental strategy into two parts:
A successful serial acquirer that doesn't issue much stock is implicitly betting everything on #1, but empirically point #2 is the main driver of seriously good returns. If you routinely buy stocks with an expected return of 10% when the market yields 7%, you beat the market by 3 points a year, which is good. If you buy with a 10% expected return and a year later your assets are priced to yield a 7% expected return, your incremental return from that repricing is 43%, which is obviously much more impressive. Those repricing events are a big driver of value's excess returns, but it's useful to separate different elements of the strategy, since after repricing a stock is no longer a value stock. The Supply-Side/Demand-Side SeesawA very good piece from Employ America argues that the chip shortage makes the case for demand-side reforms: with more demand, chip companies would have more spare capacity, and with more spare capacity, they'd be better able to adapt to supply shocks. It seems natural for this kind of decision to move in a cycle:
Chips would be an interesting test case for this, and a relatively low-risk one, for two reasons. First, there's a national security case for investing more in chips; Taiwan is at risk, and the US has a limited capacity to protect it. And second, the relatively short useful life of chip capex means that assets will be stranded for years, not decades; eventually, demand catches up, and while it's costly to overshoot, a few more years of demand growth covers a lot of temporary capital allocation sins. In other chip/China news:
1 On a personal note, one of my grandad's golfing buddies in the fifties once suggested that he ought to buy a bit of International Business Machines stock for himself. I don't know if that was a reasonable suggestion; grandpa ran a grocery store, and at the time it was still rare for anyone but the very rich to buy stocks. But we, too, could have had our story of meagre dividends and massive, but ultimately transitory, capital gains. 2 NCR is a very early case of a "business mafia," a phenomenon I've written about before. Their CEO operated on a hire-fast/fire-fast model, and because of the company's generous commissions, he was able to assemble a good sales team. Many NCR hires went on to run some of the early auto companies. 3 While George Fairchild was reluctant to invest in R&D, he did hold on to his stock, and his son Sherman had enough IBM stock to fund his interests, including aerial photography, designing movie equipment, and writing the angel check that created modern Silicon Valley. In a sense, the NCR Mafia is the direct ancestor of all subsequent tech industry mafias. 4 The original funding for their project came from the American Totalizer company, which made parimutuel betting machines. That company suspected that computers could improve betting on horses. It's an odd callback to Pascal and Fermat's early work on probability, which was also influenced by gambling. Even zero-sum financial transactions can lead to positive-sum spillovers if there’s enough money involved. 5 Just as I cynically hope that every company I respect gets sued so I'll be able to read lots of primary sources about their strategies, I cynically hope that every investor I admire goes through a drawdown. Nothing inspires soul-searching and thoughtful explanations like a few years of outflows! You’re on the free list for The Diff. For the full experience, become a paying subscriber. |
Saturday, February 27, 2021
Nuclear, TikTok, Science, Berkowitz, Housing
Friday, February 26, 2021
Plus! Technology Prosthetics; Brutal Coopetition; From Quotation System to Market-Maker; GameStop Risk; The Bull Market in Conservation
Friday, February 19, 2021
Plus! Distributed Business Clusters; More on Texas; The India Model; Clean Shipping; Price Discrimination
Saturday, February 13, 2021
Coinbase, Big Short, Amazon, Canva, Influencers, Emerging Markets, The Valley, Growth
Saturday, February 13, 2021
Plus! Facebook vs Bullying; Scale and AI; Chip Shortage Updates; Decarbonization; Supermicro, Redux
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
Rates as high as 4.50% for 12 months ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
The number of Americans anticipating to is on the rise ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
Could happen as soon as Feb 19th... ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
The Chinese Exclusion Act was the first significant crackdown on immigration in American history. We trace the factors that led to the Act and examine what happened to the economy after it passed. View
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
Boromeus Wanengkirtyo, Francesca Diluiso, Rebecca Mari, Jenny Chan, Ambrogio Cesa-Bianchi and Alex Haberis. Climate change is becoming increasingly important for monetary policy as the world
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
Francesca Diluiso, Boromeus Wanengkirtyo and Jenny Chan. This post examines key aspects of climate mitigation policies that could matter for monetary policy, using insights from structural climate
Monday, November 25, 2024
Amazon invested big in Anthropic, a hedge fund manager was tapped for the US Treasury, and quacking at the bottom of the ocean | Finimize TOGETHER WITH Hi Reader, here's what you need to know for
Monday, November 25, 2024
Plus! After Return on Equity; Operating Leverage in Media; Tech Globalization; Meta Memecoins; Accounting; Buy Low, Refi After Return on Equity By Byrne Hobart • 25 Nov 2024 View in browser View in
Monday, November 25, 2024
It's being called the world's most predictable pattern ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Saturday, November 23, 2024
Microsoft, The Study, Fraud, Electronics, Gaming, Loss Aversion, Gut, Kerkorian Longreads + Open Thread By Byrne Hobart • 23 Nov 2024 View in browser View in browser Longreads Steven Levy profiles