The Economics of Pseudonymity
Plus! Fungible Energy Jobs; Robinhood's Other IPO News; Financial Engineering in Home Improvement; The Case for Steeply Progressive Ad Taxes; Like OPEC In a Good Way
Byrne Hobart | May 21 |
You're in the free list for The Diff. This week, paid subscribers also saw:
Thanks for reading The Diff. If you'd like to support it, please subscribe. The Economics of PseudonymityPlus! Fungible Energy Jobs; Robinhood's Other IPO News; Financial Engineering in Home Improvement; The Case for Steeply Progressive Ad Taxes; Like OPEC In a Good Way
Today is the weekly free edition of The Diff, going out to 22,624readers, up 190 from last week. In this issue:
The Economics of PseudonymityPrivacy discussions come in two forms: there are nebulous worries, often articulated using the term "creepy," about how much companies learn about people’s desires and interests in the course of targeting ads. And there are also concerns about how much people can learn about one another through the Internet, and what they can do with that knowledge. Finance Twitter is full of people who don't use their real names; once, I had the disconcerting experience of meeting someone for the first time twice, once as a pseudonymous person with a cartoon Twitter avatar, and another time as a professional contact at a business meeting. Navigating this second kind of privacy situation is complicated. In the short term, changes in this kind of privacy are zero-sum, which means there's a constituency that will strongly resist any new system because they're doing fine under the existing one. More privacy for everyone means more privacy for bad people, and the more general the tools are, the more likely the bad people will be salient. Do you like political dissidents in Russia, Iran, and China more than you dislike terrorists or sex traffickers? Are "like" and "dislike" even commensurate? They have a syllable in common, but they're wildly different feelings, and people are uncomfortable trading one off against the other. Why Do We Care?Social norms haven't kept up with technology. Social shaming has always existed, and is, in fact, a pretty useful social technology; many norms have network effects. A norm against tardiness, for example, is infectious: it means that if you're going to be late, you'll be the sole reason something starts late, or it will start without you. A bit of shaming makes everyone better off. (Ecuador once ran a national PR campaign against tardiness, starring the country's Olympic gold medal winner, because of the high cost of late and uncertain meetings—if people might be upwards of half an hour late, a thirty-minute meeting requires a one hour block of time.) Shaming works inside small communities, where it's a low-cost way to maintain cohesion. It works especially well as a distributed way to maintain it: anybody is empowered to point out deviation from the norm. Some organizations take this pretty far; I've read about two cases where military units gave an "award" to the worst performer at a task while training. When you need reliability, standardization, and coordination, that's one way to get it. The trouble with online shaming is twofold:
Like a lot of other technology changes, social media takes a hardwired behavior and applies it in a new context. And this behavior is very, very hardwired.¹ The impulse isn't going to change, but the rules might—in a few different ways. Social Technology and TechnologySocial media is not the first time a new technology has made previously acceptable behavior patterns unworkable. Clay Shirky's great speech on gin and television gives two: gin was much cheaper than other forms of alcohol, and that led to the gin craze, which seems to have absorbed a truly excessive amount of England's productivity until laws and norms changed and people stopped drinking quite so much. TV has also forced some changes in norms, because it's so absorbing (and, more recently, because ubiquitous screens with bright blue light-heavy displays mean that TV can keep you awake when you're too tired to do anything except watch another episode). Plenty of modern lifestyle trends can be interpreted as reactions to technology that's a bit too rewarding:
These kinds of solutions typically blend norms and technological fixes. Often, the tech fix is a way to bootstrap the norm: it's not a complete solution, but it's a regular reminder to exert a little willpower in the right direction. Balaji Srinivasan (disclosure: I worked for him at 21) has proposed a technological solution to the newly skewed distribution of outrage: the pseudonymous economy. There are two elements here:
Here's how he describes that system:
This is a very promising sketch of an idea. There's a soft social norm that someone with credibility in one domain can start talking about some other topic and be taken more seriously than the average person. People grumble about this: what does a genetic testing entrepreneur know about cryptocurrencies, anyway? What does a crypto founder know about novel respiratory infections? As it turns out, some kinds of expertise are pretty fungible, and social media could reflect this. Life in the Pseudonymous EconomyWhat would the world look like if reputations were fungible in this way—if you could back claims with the authority of your previous accomplishments, without actually identifying yourself? For one thing, we would have known about Covid a lot earlier. One of the barriers to early Covid-panic was the fact that it was low-status to worry about disease, and very low-status to do things like hoarding food, refusing to shake hands, and putting copper tape on doorknobs. Plenty of people were privately worried well before they were publicly worried. Many of these people worked in tech, and had track records that led to substantial net worths (some of my evidence for this is anecdotal, and some of it is from the fact that Zoom's stock started outperforming the broader market in February, as Covid paranoia discreetly ratcheted up. The people who were reacting financially to Covid—using a markets as a decentralized, anonymized prediction market about current events—were disproportionately likely to phrase predictions about the future in terms of asking “which high-growth software company benefits from this trend?”). If more of them had been able to say "I won't tell you who I am, but I'm credible at the job of predicting the consequences of exponential trends, and let me tell you about a really big one," that could have shifted public discourse. But it will also lead to similarly bold predictions that don't pan out. Being able to link aggregate reputation to a view, without the reputational downside, converts an opinion from a future to a call option, and the lack of downside risk encourages the pursuit of high-variance outcomes. There's a historical precedent for this: the Tulip Bubble reached its maximum velocity when a legal ruling changed tulip contracts from futures to calls. Do the same thing for way-out-there predictions, and you get the same results: there will be a massive bull market in wildly speculative theories. A pseudonymous economy would also lead to radical compartmentalization, which would be challenging. Part of the fun of some jobs is who you get to work with, and who you get to hang out with. Separating work and social domains would be untenable; some companies form a cluster of like-minded people who are independently fun to spend time with, and under a pseudonym economy that either means irrevocably linking some of your pseudonyms or having some work-hard/play-hard pseudonyms that are tied to social networks rather than tasks. This world would also change the signaling value of showing face, in a literal sense. Someone who makes a prediction under their own name, or on video, is implicitly agreeing to own the downside as well as the upside, so it's a way to show higher confidence. Making a pseudonymous bet backed by an anonymized reputation is a way to express preemptive regret about the consequences, which colors what kinds of statements will be made that way. Taking bold reputational risk without back-linking reputation to where it came from would also turn into a Martingale-style trading strategy: each individual statement has some upside and capped reputational downside, but over time, patterns might emerge. If the system involves copyable karma, a diligent analyst might notice that 50k Karma account A stopped posting right when 45k Karma account B started, and that they both wrote at the same time of day and cited some of the same sources. If reputation is transferable, then the rule is to look for debits in one account that coincide with credits in another. (Reputation tumblers will help, but they provide statistical, not absolute, safety. And if all this activity is happening on a blockchain, then the bet is not just that the current action secures pseudonymity, but that no future action breaks it.) Right now, trusting pseudonyms is a proof-of-work system. We respect Satoshi's judgment on some topics because he did, after all, figure out Bitcoin. And we respect Banksy's ability to game the art market because we literally see the results. It could function as a proof-of-stake system instead, but, as with other proof-of-stake systems, there's a tradeoff in trust. There's some evidence that the world is moving in this direction. As Balaji points out, services like Gmail and Twitter already support multiple accounts. Part of the use case for these services is that you want to tie different things to different identities. The new round from Privacy.com, now renamed Lithic, is also evidence that people want to detach spending from identity. Lithic lets people spin up single-purpose credit cards, which a) keeps them safe from merchants who make it hard to cancel subscriptions, and b) means that they can pay for things with another intermediation layer between their payment identity and their real world identity. So there are growing layers of insulation between different personas. But the difficulty of transferring reputation without sharing identity may be a load-bearing bug in the current system. It still means reputations are somewhat fungible, but it also means that you can earn a reputation in one area and then completely trash it by doing something else. To the extent that that's a problem, it's a problem with the reputation-updating function, not with the underlying protocols. And that, like the gin boom, television, the standard American diet, or smartphone addiction, requires behavioral norms that can be boosted by, but not replaced with, new technologies. ElsewhereFungible Energy Jobs"Re-skilling" is sometimes proposed as a solution to the decline of industrial jobs: sure, there are fewer factory workers in the US than there used to be, but they can always learn to code! This is theoretically true, but my heuristic before reading any whitepaper on the topic is to Google the author and see if a think tank hired a laid-off coal miner to write it, or if they hired someone who has spent most of their career writing whitepapers. This saves time. But there is a case for reskilling happening, at least in one industry: the former RigUp, which used to focus on getting contractor workers jobs in the oil industry, is now raising more money and rebranding to WorkRise as it broadens its target industries. Notably: "Last year, Workrise placed more than 4,500 workers, or nearly a third of all its workers placed in 2020, in renewable-energy jobs. Specifically, the company says in total, it placed 8,000 unique workers in jobs in 2019, with 13% in renewables." One nice thing about WorkRise is that its entire business is built around making workers more fungible, by handling some of the administrative tasks involved in hiring them and by connecting them to multiple companies. So it's in a position to find which skills transfer, and to move people to where the growth is. Robinhood's Other IPO NewsRobinhood's S-1 is rumored to arrive any day now (stay tuned), but in the meantime they're giving their customers access to IPOs, including a 1% allocation from Figs. In December, I proposed... this:
Retail investors are less valuation-sensitive than institutional ones, so an IPO process that cuts retail investors out will lead to bigger IPO pops for recognizable companies and smaller ones for less famous or glamorous ones. Figs, which did lots of advertising to promote its clothes, is a good example of the kind of company whose name recognition could lead to an IPO pop regardless of what the ultimate price is, so it's a natural company to test this. And once there's an additional source of buying power for companies that plan to go public, it's hard for them to ignore it. Financial Engineering in Home ImprovementHearth is a SaaS product that helps contractors manage their business, including offering their customers financing; it's just raised a round. This is very similar to the economics of revenue-backed lending: the useful life of what contractors build is years or decades, so it makes sense to align the customer's payments with that. But the contractor's costs are all upfront, so it doesn't make sense for them to do the aligning. Putting a well-capitalized company in the middle lets both sides get the financial structure that makes sense. The Case for Steeply Progressive Ad TaxesPaul Romer makes an argument for a steeply progressive tax on online ad companies' revenue, mostly as a way to make powerful companies a bit less powerful. The tax is structured with marginal rates that kick in at $5bn, and rise to 72.5% for revenue over $60bn. To the extent that any plan that immediately wipes out a trillion dollars of market cap can be considered elegant, it is pretty elegant: it gives companies the flexibility to either spin off businesses (breaking up Google and YouTube, or Facebook and Instagram) or to accept punitive financial consequences. The implication of this tax is that large digital advertising businesses are, by their nature, a negative externality. If so, it's entirely appropriate to punish them in a way that scales with size. The risk is that they're also a positive externality: a company that benefits from network effects has an incentive to expand the network, and in tech companies' case that means getting more people online and making the Internet better. The same traits that make these businesses hard to dislodge, and very profitable at scale, give them an economic justification to subsidize complements that people like—good browsers, good analytics, cheap or free Internet access, etc. To calibrate a digital ad tax correctly, those benefits need to be quantified, too. And that can be a challenge, because the big ad platforms use these complements to extend their competitive advantage, which can make them reluctant to disclose details. This might be the real benefit to a proposed digital ad tax: tech companies have an incentive to under-disclose some of their strategy because the FTC wouldn't like it, but this gives them a reason to disclose more so there's a weaker case for subjecting them to a steep tax. Like OPEC In a Good WayOPEC—or, really, Saudi Arabia—used to function by adjusting the world's supply of oil in ways that benefit oil producers. The most salient way this happens is when they cut output to make prices go up; since oil consumers outnumber oil producers, this is generally unpopular. But OPEC has another function: to raise production when prices spike. This is not just a short-term profit-maximizing approach, although it looks a lot like it. One thing that makes oil assets more valuable is long-term adoption of oil-burning technologies, and that adoption is partly a function of how confident people are in the stability of prices. A massive run-up in oil is good for producers in the short term, but very bad for them in the long term if it encourages fixed investments in alternatives. So part of the cartel's job is to blunt price swings in both directions to make internal combustion engines a good risk-adjusted investment as well as a good absolute-return one. TSM occasionally gets compared to Aramco, in the sense that it's a critical input into the global economy in a geopolitically inconvenient place. And TSM is following the playbook, by increasing its output of automotive chips by 60%, at the cost of bumping other customers down in the queue ($, Nikkei). The dominant producer in a category has a different set of incentives from everyone else: they're uniquely positioned to affect how customers think about their reliance on that category of goods. And, as in this case, they're taking an economic hit in order to ensure long-term demand. 1 Elizabeth Marshall Thomas' wonderful book, The Old Way, has a brief aside in which a lecturer at Harvard describes witnessing some violent Chimpanzee behavior without qualifying that the violence was, in fact, bad. The students are horrified. Thomas: "This scene, too, was older than our species, wherein a group of primates mobs a conspecific who has temporarily fallen in status." You’re on the free list for The Diff. For the full experience, become a paying subscriber. |
Friday, May 14, 2021
Plus! Tethers and Dollars; The Hotel Shortage; The Credit Reopening; Ransomware Acceleration; Churn, Margins, and Habits
Friday, May 7, 2021
Plus! Hulu's Regulatory Arbitrage; Post-Archegos; Patents; Emissions: a Global Problem
Saturday, May 1, 2021
Platforms, Bin Laden, Ransomware, Epic, Germany
Friday, April 30, 2021
Plus! Valuementum; Quants and Lumber; Cheap Hacks; Tax Adjustment
Saturday, April 24, 2021
Cloud Kitchens, Encana, DEC, Websites, Irish Banks,
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
The Chinese Exclusion Act was the first significant crackdown on immigration in American history. We trace the factors that led to the Act and examine what happened to the economy after it passed. View
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
Boromeus Wanengkirtyo, Francesca Diluiso, Rebecca Mari, Jenny Chan, Ambrogio Cesa-Bianchi and Alex Haberis. Climate change is becoming increasingly important for monetary policy as the world
Tuesday, November 26, 2024
Francesca Diluiso, Boromeus Wanengkirtyo and Jenny Chan. This post examines key aspects of climate mitigation policies that could matter for monetary policy, using insights from structural climate
Monday, November 25, 2024
Amazon invested big in Anthropic, a hedge fund manager was tapped for the US Treasury, and quacking at the bottom of the ocean | Finimize TOGETHER WITH Hi Reader, here's what you need to know for
Monday, November 25, 2024
Plus! After Return on Equity; Operating Leverage in Media; Tech Globalization; Meta Memecoins; Accounting; Buy Low, Refi After Return on Equity By Byrne Hobart • 25 Nov 2024 View in browser View in
Monday, November 25, 2024
It's being called the world's most predictable pattern ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Saturday, November 23, 2024
Microsoft, The Study, Fraud, Electronics, Gaming, Loss Aversion, Gut, Kerkorian Longreads + Open Thread By Byrne Hobart • 23 Nov 2024 View in browser View in browser Longreads Steven Levy profiles
Saturday, November 23, 2024
Take the options trading red pill ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏
Friday, November 22, 2024
MicroStrategy raised more cash for bitcoin, Europe's business activity slipped, and going to a haunted house | Finimize TOGETHER WITH Hi Reader, here's what you need to know for November 23rd
Friday, November 22, 2024
Invest in a time-tested asset ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏ ͏